久久久无码人妻精品无码_6080YYY午夜理论片中无码_性无码专区_无码人妻品一区二区三区精99

   
  home feedback about us  
   
CHINAGATE.POVERTY RELIEF.relief_about    
    Key Issues  
 
  Policy & strategy  
  Social security  
  Education  
  Unemployment  
  Women in poverty  
  Urban poverty  
  Farmers' burden  
  Role of NGOs  
  International cooperation  
 
 
       
       
       
     
       
       
       
       
 
 
 
Poverty reduction programs' instruments(I)

2003-07-24


This section summarizes the content, implementation and impact of China's main poverty programs in the 1990s, and focuses on the investment programs which aim to promote economic and income growth to lift the poor out of poverty on a sustainable basis. Relief programs, which target a small segment of the poor, are also discussed (although they are usually regarded as distinct from the main poverty program). Implementation of the programs has been a challenge for the government, and it is believed that the efficacy of all of the programs could be substantially improved. The subsidized loan program has met difficulties in achieving its objectives. Lending to enterprises has done little to reduce poverty, and directing loans to poor households also has proved to be very difficult. These issues, compounded by low repayment rates under the program, convinced the Government to experiment with micro-credit schemes, but these have also encountered serious difficulties. The FFW program could be improved by more explicit targeting of the poorest areas, and by refocusing its work on the types of programs that bring the greatest benefits to the poor. The MOF grant program is also believed to have encountered a number of implementation difficulties, though there is scant objective information available for that program. The relief program should remain a key element of the Government's efforts, and retaining the funding and focus of this program is essential to the wellbeing of China's most destitute population. International researchers have undertaken quantitative analyses of the effectiveness of China's poverty reduction program, and have found some indications of a significant impact on living standards.

The subsidized loan program is the largest of the poverty programs and is viewed as the flagship of the Government's poverty alleviation efforts. The Government has invested about Y 68 billion in the program since its inception, and has placed considerable emphasis on trying to ensure the program reaches poor households and brings them clear benefits. However, this has proven to be extremely challenging, and the Government has tried different approaches to try to increase the effectiveness of the program.
Following earlier emphasis on issuing loans to households, in 1989 poor county governments began using a large of portion of their available subsidized poverty reduction loans to support the growth of county and township run enterprises in poor areas. In 1992 and 1993, about half of the subsidized loans were lent to industrial enterprises. Of this amount, more than 60 percent went to county run enterprises and the rest went to township run enterprises. By the mid 1990s, this policy was recognized to have been less successful than originally envisioned. Many of the rural enterprises supported in the past with poverty reduction funding have been capital intensive, loss making firms with minimal poverty reduction impact. While the number of such firms is not known, it appears that poverty reduction program funding for poor county TVE development may have even led to a net decline in revenues in some poor counties. In addition, the use of government assistance for TVE development has reduced funds and other resources available for household farm production and off-farm production undertaken by small scale private enterprises, and may have contributed to distorted patterns of development of enterprises in poor areas.

(II)

Recognizing the shortcomings of providing direct financial support, the government recently decided to severely curtail poverty reduction program funding for poor county TVE development. Instead, the more appropriate role for local governments is to establish a more favorable environment for poor county TVE development. The experience of those TVEs in poor areas which have better survived the current economic turbulence helps clarify what local government can do to facilitate TVE development. Relatively small enterprises with a more clearly defined ownership structure, operations based principally on local comparative advantage (such as cheap labor and local raw materials), and relatively large enterprises combining local resources with technology and market access provided by enterprises from more developed areas, appear to have been most successful in weathering the current economic challenges. It is therefore recommended that local governments support TVE development through (a) reforming TVE ownership and management, (b) allowing those enterprises which have negative equity and which have suffered from financial losses for a number of years to go bankrupt, and (c) encouraging local enterprises, which have operations consistent with local  comparative advantage, to establish joint ventures with enterprises from more developed areas. Past experience indicates that local governments in poor areas are not well-equipped to successfully establish and manage enterprises by themselves. These local governments should therefore instead focus on simplifying the procedures for the establishment of private and collective enterprises, reducing the taxes and other extra burdens on enterprises, improving local infrastructure, and providing more training for local accountants, auditors and technicians.
The strategy to target enterprises rather than households is in part responsible for reports from many sources showing the very low share of loans that have directly benefited poor households in the 1990s. Indeed, before 1990, some surveys indicated that 45 percent of the loans reached poor households (and one survey taken in 1987 showed 92 percent of loans reaching poor households), whereas most surveys taken during the 1990s showed much lower shares. Many observers share the sentiment expressed by a provincial official that the failure of loans to reach poor households has been the rule and not the exception. Park cites survey results showing examples of counties where none of the loans had reached the poor, and of poor villages where the majority of the loans went to farmers of average wealth and not to poor farmers.

In recognition of these failures and seeking to redirect investment directly to poor households, the 1996 National Poverty Reduction Conference decided that 70 percent of subsidized loans should reach poor households and 70 percent should be in agriculture (as opposed to industry). Early indications are that provincial and county governments appear to be making progress but have not fully achieved these targets. For example, expenditure data for Yunnan summarized in Table 3.2 below shows the balance between agricultural and industrial spending did shift after 1996. However, sizeable lending for industry remained, and the composition of spending did not reach the 70/30 stated targets. Agricultural spending increased from 27 percent to 41 percent and industrial spending decreased from 32 percent to 23 percent. The shift was most pronounced in use of central poverty loan funds (agricultural spending increased from 31 percent to 51 percent), with other funding channels also registering an increase in favor of agricultural lending. Moreover, the large increase in lending for agriculture in 1997 has not necessarily led to the intended concentration of lending away from large enterprises and to households. Provincial officials indicate that large amounts of the agricultural lending went to agricultural production bases and that loans to households comprise less than 30 percent of total agricultural spending. However, a number of field investigations by Chinese and international researchers indicate that the proportion reaching poor households is actually much lower, even as recently as 1998, when the new policy should have been fatly established.

(III)

There are a number of factors that have contributed to the program's difficulty in directing loans to poor households. The goal of the program is to both reach the poor and promote economic development, and this has led to sometimes conflicting objectives for local officials trying to carry out the program. For example, projects that will generate tax revenue have an obvious pull. Lower level officials are aware that past performance will be a criterion for more future loans, so they tend to pick projects that they perceive as bringing higher financial benefits regardless of whether or not such projects will help reduce poverty. The common perception that the poor are incapable of managing projects successfully also contributes to the preference for lending to enterprises (and richer households).
Even when official policy succeeds in directing loans directly down to the household level, there are a number of actors which contribute to diversion of loans to nonpoor households. First of all, favorable loan terms (the annual interest rate is 2.88 percent) and large loan size leads to strong competition from the nonpoor. Procedures for loan application and approval are complicated, and this tends to discourage poor applicants. The problem of loan guarantees and collateral is also a significant factor. For example, to guarantee repayment of the loans, ABC requires physical collateral which often leads to exclusion of poor households from the program. And ABC's obligation to bear the burden of the repayment risk conflicts with its role as a commercial bank, and many loans are diverted to commercial purposes and to richer households. Moreover, in 1998, ABC began passing down the repayment risk to local cadres and governments, which in turn pass the risk down to village councils. Not surprisingly, village councils often balk at lending to poor households. Inadequate monitoring and supervision capability of the local PADOs exacerbates the problems in implementing these programs.

In addition to the difficulties in targeting the poor, repayment of the government loan programs has been an issue. The most extensive survey on repayment was carried out by the China Science and Technology Commission between 1991-1993. That survey indicated that repayment levels averaged 54 percent, which is well below sustainable rates. Overdue loans were greater than 100 percent of all loans coming to term. Repayment of loans to enterprises was the lowest at less than 40 percent. In addition to the lax supervision and monitoring efforts, low and negative real interest rates serve as a disincentive for repayment. Also, good repayment does not necessarily lead to additional loans (Park, 1998). Official data from Yunnan shows only a 39 percent repayment rate in 1997, with overdue loans representing over 100 percent of newly issued loans.

(IV)

Microcredit Programs. In response to the growing realization that government poverty loan programs were not reaching the poor and to the low repayment rates of the programs, and awareness of successful microcredit programs in China and abroad, the government began experimenting with using the subsidized poverty loan funds for microcredit activities. The Government's use of subsidized poverty loan funds for microcredit has expanded rapidly. In 1997, the program included more than 80 counties, and had invested more than Y 100 million. By 1998, it was reported to have reached 200 counties, and total investment was about Y 800 million. Most government funded microfinance programs have used variations of the Grameen Bank approach, which has been employed successfully in other countries, and in some donor programs in China. Initially, the program was organized by the PADOs, which lent the funds directly to households.

Relatively high arrears rates in a number of the government's programs led to a recent switch in the microcredit system, and regulations now require that microfinance experiments using subsidized loans be undertaken by ABC, rather than the PADOs. Loan contracts are to be signed between the ABC and households. The role of the PADOs will be to focus on organizing households into groups and centers and facilitating loan repayment. This move addresses weaknesses in financial management and supervision, which has been one of the central problems
in the government schemes. However, ABC's current institutional capacity is likely to hinder its ability to undertake Grameen type microfinance experiments as many county ABCs do not have agencies and staff at the township level. Moreover, the loan commission to be paid by ABC to the PADOs for their work in organizing groups and repayment is most likely too small to sustain their interest in microcredit.

Well designed microcredit programs can avoid many of the pitfalls seen in subsidized credit programs around the world, and which have plagued China's poverty loan program. In designing any future role for microcredit in the Government's poverty program, a number of points should be emphasized. First, microcredit on its own is unlikely to meet the needs of the absolute poor, and should be combined with other types of interventions in the poorest areas. Second, improved financial management, monitoring, supervision and internal auditing, backed up by intensive staff training, are key to the success of any microcredit program. Lax or non-existent systems made government experiments with microcredit vulnerable to spiraling repayment problems, and financial mismanagement. Third, programs should avoid the tendency to become top-down, and may wish to experiment with devolving response stability for implementation to grassroots organizations. It probably would be advantageous for the PADOs to play a role in monitoring and supervising microcredit, but to have the actual programs managed by organizations outside the government structure. At a minimum, staff should be hired by open recruitment and not be appointed by county or other officials. One positive aspect of the Green model is that its participatory methods promote initiative among the poor by encouraging them to form groups, choose group leaders, and decide their own investments. If programs side step this "bottom-up" approach, this aspect is lost, and targeting and repayment can also suffer. Fourth, government programs have tended to charge rates of interest well below the level that would allow them to cover operating costs. This can lead to leakage of funds to the non-poor, and also threatens the sustainability of the programs. Finally, the current group based models can be quite costly, both to the poor and in terms of administrative costs (for example, through frequent group meetings and repayment). Impact assessment should be undertaken to better understand the costs and benefits to the poor of existing programs, and to assess whether variations on the current models might be better suited to some areas.

(V)

In the longer term, mechanisms to provide credit for the poor could take many forms. Developing savings services could be even more important for poor farmers than credit services, but no savings should be organized until prudential regulation and supervision has been established. Reforming existing financial institutions in poor areas may be the most efficient way to reach large numbers of poor and near poor, but this should not preclude a future role for informal financial organizations that now lend to the poor. Some of the current temporary microfinance program offices could possibly be converted more permanent institutions, if they are able to meet appropriate performance and regulatory standards. Small, grass-roots organizations have the potential to play a role in piloting innovative techniques and their strong outreach is invaluable.

The FFW program, implemented by the State Development Planning Commission, provides funding for infrastructure construction in poor areas. The program originally made use of left over commodity stocks which were distributed to counties, which used a coupon system to pay for inputs and labor done under the program. Funding from the program in the early years went almost entirely to rural roads, water, and land improvement. After large increases in the program beginning in the early 1990s, the program has diversified and includes investments in a much larger number of areas including water conservation, and even commerce, education and health. Central government funds are supposed to be matched by provincial and county funds. However, in most cases, matched funds are inadequate. This has meant that central funds are entirely used for construction inputs, and the shortage in funds is offset by the use of voluntary labor contributions from villagers. (In most areas of rural China, villages operate a "work day contribution system," with each villager obligated to work a certain number of days annually. FFW labor contribution is deducted from this annual requirement). Zhu and Jiang (1996) estimate that 40 percent of labor used for FFW construction is free labor. In general, the types of investment (for example, water, roads, land improvement) are made by national and provincial governments. County governments select the villages to participate in the program, and village committees make decisions on the allocation of project investments (for example, which areas should be terraced) and labor contribution. There have been few systematic evaluations of the FFW program, but most reports indicate that the program has done a relatively good job in constructing a good deal of infrastructure that has benefited poor areas.

From analysis based on data from FFW projects in the early 1990s, it appears that villages with more favorable economic conditions, those in more remote areas, and those with higher populations have been more likely to receive FFW projects (Zhu and Jiang, 1996). The poorest villages are less likely to receive these projects. In some cases it may be a rational economic decision to omit some of the poorest villages from FFW projects based on evaluation of economic returns. Building a road or providing electricity in a remote, sparsely populated village, for example, would in many cases not be the most efficient use of poverty reduction funds. Nevertheless, it would appear that the impact of the program on the poor could be improved by greater efforts to select poorer villages. Indeed, in the mid 1990s, more remote areas were said to be targeted for FFW projects, but results from these efforts have not yet been assessed. 

(VI)

Village committees are generally charged with selecting participants for labor work under FFW, and most assessments indicate this is done in an equitable manner. In general, each household is assigned a certain number of days of FFW work, based on the household's labor supply. However, because labor provided under FFW schemes is in many cases, unpaid labor, households with higher cash earnings sometimes choose not to participate and contribute an equivalent sum of money. Some observers have criticized the free labor contribution as a "labor tax" which falls disproportionately on the poor who are most likely to contribute labor to the scheme. While this tax may not be high, since typically the labor takes place in the off-season when there is limited alternative work to be done, the program would probably bring higher benefits to the poor if all work was paid, even if this reduced the total amount of infrastructure built. (Zhu and Jiang, 1996, Park, 1999). International experience has shown that public works schemes, using wage rates below the current wage, are very effective poverty alleviation measures. FFW would do well to experiment with such schemes in order to better reduce poverty and provide some insurance that those who have escaped poverty don't fall back below the poverty line. As such, using FFW as part of a public works scheme could form an important part of China's emerging social safety net.

The program is administered in a fairly top down manner, and in some cases the actual project investments are contrary to villagers expressed needs. For example, Zhu and Jiang document a case where villagers voiced a clear need and preference for more roads, but were instead told to build terraces by county officials. In addition, both domestic and international observers have suggested that infrastructure built under the program would have a greater effect if it were integrated with other investments that benefit the poor. 

Finally, there are also concerns that the expansion of the program in the mid 1990s, has diluted the effectiveness of the program and its impact on the poor, and led to some laxity in funds management. Zhu and Jiang point out that some of the investments included in FFW in the 1990s have no direct relation to poverty reduction (for example investments in rural post offices). Also, the large number of sectors and line ministries now involved means that the matching funds shortage has become more acute, and many projects are left unfinished, and project funding is often too diluted to have sufficient impact. Supervision of funds usage has also become more complicated and there have been reports of funds diversion.  for poor areas is provided through earmarked grants for education, a revolving fund, and also tax incentives and budgetary subsidies.

MOF grant funds have grown very slowly, decreasing in real terms from the late 1980s and not recovering their 1986 value until 1998. MOF grant funding has not been carefully investigated, and there is little published evaluation of its efficacy. There are a number of implementation problems with the grant schemes including difficulty in raising counterpart funds, diversion of funds to pay administrative costs, unclear authority over fund use, slow and late delivery of funds not synchronized to project needs, and dispersion of funds which precludes economies of scale in project investments.

(VII)

China's rural relief system, implemented by the Ministry of Civil Affairs and provincial and county Civil Affairs bureaus, is independent from the government's poverty relief program. Nonetheless, many recipients of the program are members of China's poor population. The bulk of the program targets those affected by natural disaster, such as earthquakes, flood and drought. A much lesser share of the rural relief program funding is directed to those considered truly destitute, who lack any means or potential to support themselves. Members of this second group are guaranteed food, clothing, housing, medical care, and funds for burial, and education (for orphans). These are referred to as the "five guarantees" in Chinese. Provincial governments provide most of the budgetary funds for the program, but the system also receives donations from other sources. Township level governments use funds allocated from the county Bureaus to purchase necessities (including grain, clothing and blankets) for relief recipients. It is generally prohibited to give money directly to relief recipients.
Snapshots of the program in Ningxia and Yunnan indicate that the program has increased in size over time, and that its functions have been maintained. In Ningxia, interviews with Jingyuan County officials indicated that most of the funds are used for disaster relief, and funds used for the "sanwu" group accounts for only a very small proportion of the total budget. In 1996, for example, the county had a total budget of about Y 1.22 million yuan for relief purposes, of which, Y 1.10 million was used for disaster relief, and only Y 0.12 million used for the "sanwu" group. In 1998, Y 1.01 million was used for natural disaster relief out of a Y 1.27 million total budget. Most funds for natural disaster relief money go towards food consumption. The Jingyuan County officials reported their belief that the effectiveness of the program has increased over time.

In Yunnan, interviews with county officials also indicated that the program has expanded in step with economic growth. The size of the provincial rural relief program budget increased from Y 46 million in 1990 to Y 132 million in 1998. As in Ningxia, most funds were used for disaster relief. In Luquan County, for example, the total budget for the relief program was Y 1.21 million, of which, Y 0.94 million was used for disaster relief. In 1998, the pattern was similar with Y 2.22 million used for disaster relief out of a total Y 2.99 million budget. However, provincial officials claim that an increase in the frequency of natural disasters has offset the budget increases. For example, in Luquan County, the total area affected by natural disaster increased from 39,000 mu in 1991 to 143,000 mu in 1998. In Yunnan, natural disaster relief activities mainly focus on food, clothing, housing and basic medical care.

Historically, the relief system has functioned well in providing a safety for the most destitute and preventing starvation during the most severe circumstances. It appears that concerns that reform of the grain marketing system might undermine the effectiveness of the system have not come to pass, and that funding (at least in the provinces cited above) has been maintained in real terms. It is important that the focus and the intensity of the program continue. Recent government pronouncements on intentions of setting up a stronger safety set, that would seem intended to cover rural as well as urban areas, are a positive sign.

 
   
 
home feedback about us  
  Produced by www.ttav89.com. All Rights Reserved
E-mail: webmaster@chinagate.com.cn
久久久无码人妻精品无码_6080YYY午夜理论片中无码_性无码专区_无码人妻品一区二区三区精99

    国产精品私人影院| 一级女性全黄久久生活片免费| 国产精品一区二区无线| 国产三级欧美三级日产三级99 | 亚洲综合自拍偷拍| 91精品在线免费| 国产中文一区二区三区| 国产女人aaa级久久久级 | 色欧美日韩亚洲| 天天综合天天综合色| 精品国产一区久久| 成人午夜激情视频| 亚洲综合色区另类av| 日韩欧美不卡一区| 成人丝袜视频网| 婷婷夜色潮精品综合在线| 日韩女优制服丝袜电影| av日韩在线网站| 婷婷综合另类小说色区| 久久九九影视网| 欧美亚洲综合另类| 韩国av一区二区| 一区二区国产视频| 免费人成精品欧美精品| 欧美韩国一区二区| 欧美日本免费一区二区三区| 国产最新精品精品你懂的| 一区二区三区欧美在线观看| 欧美刺激脚交jootjob| 国产99精品国产| 五月天亚洲婷婷| 国产精品久久毛片av大全日韩| 欧美日韩精品一区二区在线播放| 国产一区视频在线看| 一区二区三区四区高清精品免费观看| 欧美草草影院在线视频| 色综合久久天天综合网| 久久国产视频网| 一区二区三区在线观看国产| 欧美不卡激情三级在线观看| 色婷婷av一区| 国产激情偷乱视频一区二区三区 | 精品一区二区在线播放| 亚洲免费观看高清完整版在线观看熊 | 欧美老肥妇做.爰bbww| 成人一区二区三区视频| 日韩国产一二三区| 亚洲天堂精品视频| 精品国产一区a| 欧美色视频在线| 成人蜜臀av电影| 久久精品国产**网站演员| 亚洲老司机在线| 国产三级精品视频| 日韩一区二区三区在线视频| 色欧美日韩亚洲| 粉嫩av一区二区三区在线播放| 日韩制服丝袜av| 一区二区三区国产精华| 国产日韩欧美在线一区| 欧美一区二区三区视频免费播放| 99久久精品国产导航| 久久66热偷产精品| 亚洲成人777| 1000精品久久久久久久久| 26uuu另类欧美亚洲曰本| 欧美日韩精品福利| 99久久久无码国产精品| 国产精品中文有码| 日本麻豆一区二区三区视频| 亚洲线精品一区二区三区 | 偷拍与自拍一区| 一区二区三区欧美激情| 国产精品久久久久一区二区三区共| 欧美成人vr18sexvr| 欧美精品一二三区| 在线观看亚洲专区| 99精品久久只有精品| 粉嫩蜜臀av国产精品网站| 韩国午夜理伦三级不卡影院| 免费看日韩a级影片| 亚洲成人精品一区二区| 亚洲自拍都市欧美小说| 亚洲日本电影在线| 中文字幕一区二| 国产精品毛片高清在线完整版| 国产欧美一区二区三区在线看蜜臀| 久久综合资源网| 精品乱人伦小说| 精品福利一区二区三区| 日韩美女视频在线| 日韩三级免费观看| 日韩视频中午一区| 日韩一区二区在线观看| 欧美一区二区三区视频在线观看 | 久久蜜臀中文字幕| 精品成人在线观看| 久久综合狠狠综合久久综合88 | 三级欧美在线一区| 爽好久久久欧美精品| 午夜精品一区二区三区三上悠亚| 亚洲午夜在线视频| 午夜国产不卡在线观看视频| 亚洲不卡一区二区三区| 丝袜美腿亚洲综合| 日韩影视精彩在线| 麻豆精品视频在线| 久久不见久久见免费视频7| 精品影视av免费| 国产一区二区三区在线观看精品| 国产一区二区女| 丰满放荡岳乱妇91ww| 成人av免费在线观看| 91免费在线播放| 欧美日韩一区在线观看| 欧美军同video69gay| 日韩欧美色电影| 久久影院视频免费| 国产精品妹子av| 亚洲久本草在线中文字幕| 亚洲国产日韩一区二区| 日韩精彩视频在线观看| 经典三级一区二区| 成人黄页毛片网站| 色视频一区二区| 宅男噜噜噜66一区二区66| 亚洲丰满少妇videoshd| 日本欧美韩国一区三区| 国产原创一区二区三区| 成人黄色在线看| 欧美性大战久久久久久久蜜臀 | 欧美一级片免费看| 久久嫩草精品久久久久| 中文字幕一区二区三区在线不卡| 一区二区三区日韩| 久久成人免费网| 成人午夜精品一区二区三区| 在线观看视频一区| 日韩欧美一区在线观看| 欧美激情综合网| 夜夜揉揉日日人人青青一国产精品| 人人超碰91尤物精品国产| 国产不卡一区视频| 91福利社在线观看| 精品日韩在线一区| 亚洲丝袜另类动漫二区| 蜜臀精品久久久久久蜜臀| 成人激情电影免费在线观看| 欧美视频一区在线观看| 久久伊99综合婷婷久久伊| 亚洲精品视频在线| 麻豆91在线看| 91在线观看一区二区| 91精品国模一区二区三区| 亚洲国产高清在线| 婷婷国产在线综合| 国产成人三级在线观看| 欧美日韩视频第一区| 久久久精品欧美丰满| 亚洲一区二区综合| 国产成人午夜精品5599| 欧美日韩aaaaa| 中文一区一区三区高中清不卡| 亚洲成人av福利| 成人免费观看视频| 日韩一区二区三区在线| 亚洲日本成人在线观看| 黄色小说综合网站| 欧美性受xxxx| 亚洲国产成人私人影院tom| 亚洲h精品动漫在线观看| 国产91对白在线观看九色| 欧美精品 国产精品| 中文字幕在线免费不卡| 老汉av免费一区二区三区| 在线免费一区三区| 国产欧美日韩综合| 日韩中文字幕不卡| 色琪琪一区二区三区亚洲区| 久久精品一区蜜桃臀影院| 日韩高清不卡一区| 色噜噜狠狠成人中文综合| 国产亚洲欧洲997久久综合| 亚洲一区视频在线| 99久久99久久免费精品蜜臀| 337p日本欧洲亚洲大胆精品| 亚洲va欧美va国产va天堂影院| av电影一区二区| 久久久久亚洲蜜桃| 日日夜夜免费精品| 欧洲精品一区二区| 国产精品美女久久久久av爽李琼| 久久电影网站中文字幕| 在线不卡欧美精品一区二区三区| 亚洲日本护士毛茸茸| 成人免费看视频| 久久久电影一区二区三区| 九一久久久久久| 69堂精品视频| 亚洲国产欧美在线|