Comment
    Free trade and globalization
    2009-Oct-9 08:09:22

    A July 2009 World Bank report shows that anti-dumping, safeguard and other trade barriers are currently in vogue, despite the fact that state leaders vowed at the London G20 summit not to do so in the wake of the global economic crisis. The report warns that the present year-to-date pace of new safeguard investigations is likely to make 2009 the second most prolific year since the WTO's inception in 1995. Not surprisingly, the surge in domestic protectionist pressures stems from the negative impacts of free trade on income disparity, as evidenced by worsening inequality in about two-thirds of the countries between 1990 and 2005. Rising impoverishment alongside burgeoning largesse of the already rich, poses a major threat to global social harmony.

    Free trade is essential for maximization of global economic welfare, rewarding "factors of production" according to their productivity, thus allowing nations and individuals to exploit respective "comparative advantages". Free trade also frees individuals from the shackles of local tyranny, tradition and provincialism. Globalization is a sine qua non for free trade, promoting benefits that are ubiquitous, compelling, and incontrovertible. Globally, a stunning 135 million people escaped dire poverty between 1999 and 2004; this being more than the population of Japan or Russia, with favorable impact on more people, more quickly, than at any other time in history.

    Although developing countries' income levels have been catching up with rich countries in this globalization era, the problem is that income disparity is widening within nations and between individuals. Within-country income distribution has become worse virtually everywhere. In China, for instance, urban-to-rural household per capita income in 2004 was 3.2 times, and the coastal-to-inland GDP per capita was 2.4 times; these differentials being amongst the highest in the world. Moreover, China is but a microcosm of increasing global income disparities. For instance, over the past decade, inequality has increased in 13 out of 18 Asian countries.

    There are three lines of explanation for free trade/globalization failing to narrow country and global income inequalities, as theory would suggest. First, the assumption of "perfect competition" is an ideal, rather than a reality. Even the father of free-market economics, Adam Smith, admitted that government restrictions on trade, particularly in critical sectors, such as defense and, more broadly, the public sector, are essential for national development. Ironically, globalization's greatest evangelists are the very same country officials that stealthily erect protectionist trade barriers (via import quotas and tariffs) and under-cut competitive forces (through subsidies). This unfair competition creates "artificial" comparative advantages, destroying free trade benefits, and imposing high costs on local consumers and developing country exporters, alike.

    The second explanation for the growth-equity paradox is that the search for comparative advantage is based on factor endowment; the so-called Heckscher-Ohlin theorem. The reality, however, is that this development strategy can best be described as a "race to the bottom" by poor economies. These states seek to attract foreign direct investment (FDI) with promises of cheap labor and big competitive tax breaks. The result is suppressed poverty wages, often below subsistence levels, in developing countries. As a consequence, the average wage of US' top 10 trading partners fell between the 1980s and 1990s, somewhat tarnishing globalization's luster. In contrast, senior managers in less developed economies are left with more disposable income when compared to their Western counterparts, further stressing income disparity in emerging countries.

    The final explanation, more worryingly, is that even if the international trade system runs exactly as theory suggests, the existing global financial architecture remains problematical because it represents a division of labor favoring rich-country knowledge-intensive exporters, whilst emerging economies mainly concentrate on exporting raw materials and low value-added goods. This "static" comparative advantage causes unacceptably high unemployment, the loss of potentially efficient industries, and results in irresponsible resource exploitation in emerging economies; the latter, as a consequence, face the dilemma of needing a buy-in to the globalization phenomenon, but by doing so, suffer from exclusive reliance on low value-added sectors.

    The danger of widening income disparities is that a tidal wave of rage against globalization is building. Yet, the greatest threat to globalization does not come from the awakening of working people in developing countries, and the poor in advanced ones, but, perversely, from the rich and powerful states failing to address the perceived and real deficiencies and "unfairness" of the present international trading and financial system. Bubbling to the surface are the twin evils of protectionism and economic nationalism. The policy response has been to more equitably share the gains from globalization, and some truly innovative policies have been introduced, such as the "UN Millennium Development Goals", social safety nets, and a variety of humanitarian assistance programs. These measures aim to transfer resources from rich to poor countries; they are thus meaningful, but only time will tell whether they will provide full or just partial economic antidotes to poverty.

    For emerging economies, social policy is the "flip-side" of an open economy. To avoid trading-off poverty reduction by chipping away the benefits of globalization, social policy should have a dual function: it must enhance social engagement in decision-making, but at the time same, give social direction to poverty reduction. Such a flexible, more socially responsible, approach to trade and development enables anti-globalization "radicals" to obtain a legitimate voice in support of greater social enterprise.

    Moreover, organizations and charities aligned with the anti-globalization movement should be entitled to participate in global conferences. Such fora would provide excellent opportunities for pushing advocacy goals in civil society and democratizing global policy-making, hence compensating losers from globalization. Violent protest, made worse by non-involved anarchist groupings, would thus, hopefully, give way to peaceful and constructive dialog.

    Harmonious development demands the evolution of "social enterprise" without jeopardizing profit-driven business models. The social enterprise concept embroiders "blended" value objectives into mission statements, focusing on sustainable profit but not at the cost of social and environmental imperatives, critical for securing poverty reduction. Moreover, as a form of social enterprise, micro-credit banks have been designed to combat poverty in developing countries.

    Wang Di is a researcher at the S. Rajaratnam School of International Studies (RSIS), Nanyang Technological University. Ron Matthews is a professor and deputy director of the Institute of Defense and Strategic Studies at RSIS.

    (China Daily 10/09/2009 page8)

    [Jump to ]
    Nation | Biz | Comment | World | Celebrity | Odds | Sports | Travel | Health
    ChinaDaily Mobile News
    m.chinadaily.com.cn
    To subscribe to China Daily, call 010-64918763 or email to circu@chinadaily.com.cn
    国产在线观看无码免费视频 | 亚洲AV中文无码乱人伦下载| 久久国产三级无码一区二区| 亚洲天堂2017无码中文| 天堂无码久久综合东京热| 在线精品无码字幕无码AV| 在线中文字幕av| 无码人妻一区二区三区在线水卜樱 | 亚洲AV无码一区二区二三区入口 | 国产成人三级经典中文| 国产a v无码专区亚洲av| 性无码专区一色吊丝中文字幕| 无码人妻丰满熟妇区五十路| 性无码免费一区二区三区在线| 色综合久久最新中文字幕| 日韩电影无码A不卡| 久久精品国产亚洲AV无码麻豆| 中文字幕av高清有码| 亚洲一区二区三区无码中文字幕 | 制服丝袜中文字幕在线| 久久久无码精品午夜| 久久久久亚洲AV无码网站| 亚洲中文久久精品无码ww16| 亚洲精品无码AV中文字幕电影网站| 中文字幕久久精品无码| 无码人妻少妇久久中文字幕| 国产成人无码免费看片软件 | 97碰碰碰人妻视频无码| 少妇无码一区二区三区免费| 亚洲综合av永久无码精品一区二区 | 久久亚洲av无码精品浪潮 | 丰满岳乱妇在线观看中字无码 | 亚洲人成网亚洲欧洲无码久久| 国产成人无码免费看视频软件 | 免费无码黄网站在线看| 亚洲欧洲中文日韩av乱码| 最近中文字幕免费完整| 暖暖免费中文在线日本| 日韩乱码人妻无码中文字幕视频| 最好看的中文字幕最经典的中文字幕视频 | 亚洲日韩精品无码专区网址|