Comment
    Check borrowings by local govts
    2010-Jun-2 07:48:52

    Imposing a ceiling on local government debt could prevent a Greek-style crisis from erupting on the mainland

    While parts of the world are dealing with the aftermath of the financial crisis or an emerging sovereign-debt crisis, China is coping with the risk of overheating and/or an asset bubble.

    Many factors may be pushing China's economy in this direction. One of the most worrying is the same factor that fueled the current crisis in the Eurozone - mushrooming public debt.

    In the Eurozone, the problem is member countries' sovereign debt; in China, the problem is borrowing linked to local governments.

    In the Eurozone, a bloated social-welfare system, particularly for the rapidly growing population of retirees, and the economic slowdown caused by the financial crisis are key components of the structural debt problem. In China, it has been caused due to increased borrowing by local officials in order to ensure that their regions' economic growth rates remain at double-digit levels.

    There are, no surprise, commonalities between China and the Eurozone. Obviously, debt accumulates wherever people want to spend more than they have saved. But a more specific similarity is that highly indebted Eurozone countries and Chinese provinces and counties have been spending too much of a common currency.

    Because these funds are not issued or controlled by any member country or local government, Eurozone members and Chinese local governments cannot relieve their debt problems through devaluation. So, in both cases, when a debt is defaulted upon or loans become non-performing, the negative consequences are felt by the entire financial and monetary "zone" - the entire EU and all of China. To avoid such an internal "sovereign debt crisis," China's Budget Law, adopted in 1994, forbade local governments from borrowing autonomously, either by issuing bonds to the public or by getting credit from banks. In theory, this means that local governments cannot finance their deficits by increasing their debt levels, because they can borrow only from the central government or other central authorities.

    But the Budget Law did not put an end to the problem. While local governments have been unable to borrow, locally controlled state-investment companies can. So it is no surprise that a huge volume of bank loans has passed through the local branches of state-owned banks to finance local public-investment projects.

    These borrowings caused a surge in non-performing bank loans in the early and mid-1990s, when total non-performing loans hit 40 percent of GDP. This caused a credit crunch and prolonged deflation in the late 1990s, as the central government tried to clean up the mess.

    Due to privatization of State-owned enterprises and improved financial regulation, including bank supervision and risk control, since 2000 both central and local budgets have basically been in good order. The ratio of total public debt to GDP was less than 22 percent in 2007-2008, before the global financial crisis. There was still some borrowing by local governments, of course, but on a limited scale (totaling 3-4 percent of GDP), owing to institutionalized surveillance of lending.

    Then came the financial crisis, with the central government adopting fiscal stimulus and relaxing monetary policy. Local governments were encouraged to increase their spending on public infrastructure projects in order to maintain growth. As a result, the volume of bank credit financing local investments increased six-fold in 2009 alone. Indeed, total borrowing by local governments now amounts to roughly $900 billion, up from $150 billion year on year and the equivalent of almost 20 percent of GDP.

    This level of borrowing poses a new type of financial risk for China. But how big and dangerous is that risk?

    I believe that it remains manageable. Some local borrowing can be justified by the central budgetary allocation to local projects. Moreover, some local spending took place in regions that will continue to enjoy high growth in tax revenues for the foreseeable future, thus ensuring that the debts will be serviced. Perhaps only one-third of the total volume of loans is problematic; the rest may or will continue to perform.

    The most important change that may keep the problem manageable is that China's monetary authorities have applied the brakes on the growth of these kinds of debt since late last year. In general, local borrowing windows are closed, and inspections are underway to gain an accurate picture of the situation. With economic growth continuing, the potential risk posed by this debt will diminish.

    Chinese officials are drawing lessons from this heavy debt burden, as they fear the prospect of local governments creating an internal "Greek crisis" for the rest of the country. The authorities recognize the need for strict fiscal discipline and financial regulation. The leverage of any public entity must be monitored, supervised, and restricted.

    Of course, Chinese local governments have never had total financial or fiscal autonomy. Indeed, ever since the Qin Dynasty (221-206 BC) united the country and established a centralized regime some 2,000 years ago, accountability for debt has been treated as a central government problem. Those who advocate fiscal decentralization and deregulation in China should think about establishing real local fiscal accountability first.

    China's current legal framework contributed to fiscal balance and financial stability in the past, and it continues to play a positive role. Otherwise, China might already have experienced its own localized "sovereign debt" crisis and, perhaps, hyperinflation.

    But when local governments are barred from debt finance, they look for other means. For example, they try to squeeze as much as possible out of land sales, thereby pushing up housing prices and helping to inflate asset bubbles.

    Given the negative consequences of this approach, it might be wise for the central government to consider establishing, for the short-run, quotas or ceilings for total local government borrowing. But, in the long run, China's fiscal and financial stability will be ensured only by systematic institutional reform of central-local government relationships.

    The author is professor of Economics at Peking University and the Chinese Academy of Social Sciences.

    (China Daily 06/02/2010 page8)

    [Jump to ]
    Nation | Biz | Comment | World | Celebrity | Odds | Sports | Travel | Health
    ChinaDaily Mobile News
    m.chinadaily.com.cn
    To subscribe to China Daily, call 010-64918763 or email to circu@chinadaily.com.cn
    国产Av激情久久无码天堂| 中文字幕丰满乱孑伦无码专区| 亚洲成?Ⅴ人在线观看无码| 无码国产精品一区二区免费虚拟VR | 狠狠精品久久久无码中文字幕| 免费A级毛片无码A∨中文字幕下载| 亚洲综合av永久无码精品一区二区 | 好看的中文字幕二区高清在线观看 | 中文字幕一精品亚洲无线一区| 亚欧免费无码aⅴ在线观看| 亚洲av午夜国产精品无码中文字 | 伊人久久大香线蕉无码麻豆| 无码人妻精品一区二区三区夜夜嗨| 最好看更新中文字幕| 中文字幕av无码一区二区三区电影 | 中文字幕精品视频在线| 中文一国产一无码一日韩| 久久久无码精品午夜| 久久精品aⅴ无码中文字字幕不卡| 高清无码午夜福利在线观看| 无码中文字幕日韩专区| 国产 欧美 亚洲 中文字幕| 无码AⅤ精品一区二区三区| 国产精品无码无卡无需播放器| 久久精品aⅴ无码中文字字幕不卡 久久精品aⅴ无码中文字字幕重口 | 青青草无码免费一二三区| 永久免费av无码网站yy| 国精品无码一区二区三区在线蜜臀| 最新中文字幕在线视频| 久久久久综合中文字幕| 日韩免费在线中文字幕| 最近中文字幕电影大全免费版| а中文在线天堂| 精品久久久久久久久久中文字幕| 亚洲久本草在线中文字幕| 久久精品天天中文字幕人妻 | 日韩区欧美区中文字幕| 中文字幕在线免费| 熟妇人妻系列av无码一区二区| 中文字幕不卡亚洲| 亚洲国产成人片在线观看无码|