We have launched E-mail Alert service,subscribers can receive the latest catalogues free of charge

     
     
    You Are Here: Home > Publications> Articles

    Growth of Productivity and Sustainable Economic Growth in China

    2002-12-13

    Li Shantong, Hou Yongzhi, Wu Yanrui and Liu Peilin Research Report No 108, 2002

    China has maintained a high-speed economic growth for two decades since 1978. With the start of the new century, the Chinese economy has also entered a new phase of development. Whether or not Chinese economy can maintain its rapid growth during this new period of history has aroused wide concern at home and abroad.

    The answer to this question lies in one’s understanding of the performance of Chinese economy, especially the understanding of the role of productivity in China’s economic growth over the past 20 years. This paper will first present an analytical framework and then examine China’s productivity growth in the past and its trend of development in the future. Finally, we will shed some light on the sustainable growth of the Chinese economy.

    I. The Analytical Framework: An Extended Solow Approach

    1. Documentary origins of the analytical approach used in this paper

    The analytical approach adopted in this paper has two documentary origins: the analytical framework for calculating growth proposed by Solow in 1957, and the method for measuring technological efficiency put forward by Farrell et al..

    According to Solow’s analytical framework, economic growth is decomposed into input of key factors and contribution from improvement of efficiency of all factors, as shown in the following equation:

    Growth of Productivity and Sustainable Economic Growth in China

    In this formula, Y represents the growth rate of output, F stands for the growth rate of key factors of production, αi, meanwhile, indicates the proportion of the remunerations of various key factors of production in output. (The sum total of the remunerations of various key factors in production under the condition of full competition and neutrality of scale remuneration is 1, precisely. In other words, the remunerations of various key factors of production divide up total output completely.) stands for the growth rate of productivity of key factors of production. The economic meaning commonly attributed to it is technological progress.

    As a matter of fact, however, what measures is the result of joint action of multiple factors. According to recent documentary progress, can be further decomposed into two parts: (1). Movement of production function itself, or technological progress in a stricter sense. (2). Effect of changes in output resulting from changes in technological efficiency. To explain the second effect, it is necessary to define the concept of technological efficiency at first.

    As is known to all, what production function stands for is the maximum output achieved by an industry under the condition of best software and management expertise. But the actual output level set by many economic entities under the condition of certain input is usually lower than that of their potential output. The difference between actual and potential output levels is technological efficiency. Diagram 1 shows the meaning of technological efficiency under the condition of input of a single key factor. The x axle in the diagram stands for the amount of input of the key factor, the y axle represents output, and TE1 and TE2 show the technological efficiency when the level of input stays at x1 and x2 respectively. Farrell (1957), Aigner, Lovell, Schmidt (1977), and Meeusen and van den Broech (1977) have constructed a method for measuring technological efficiency.

    Diagram 1: Meaning of technological efficiency

    Growth of Productivity and Sustainable Economic Growth in China

    If the method developed by Farrell et al. is used, the in Solow’s framework can be divided into two parts -- technological progress and change of technological efficiency, thus deepening analyses of productivity and economic growth.

    So far as China is concerned, economic reform influences productivity growth through two channels, theoretically. One is to improve the utilization efficiency of existing resources, that is, to improve the output level by way of revolution to let it approach the possible frontier of production (to improve technological efficiency), the another channel is to promote innovation and invention, that is, technological progress. It helps a lot to review the changes that have taken place in China’s productivity, especially the changes that have taken place in the two component parts of productivity, when we try to understand the root cause of China’s economic growth over the past two decades and forecast its prospect in the future. To this end, the paper extends the traditional Solow method by integrating it with the method mentioned above to construct a new analytical framework for studying productivity and economic growth.

    2. The method adopted in this paper and its characteristics

    The basic production function used in this paper is transcendental logarithmic production function. The key factors of production involved include input of capital and labour forces. The following assumptions have been included in the model designing: (1). The remunerations of production scale remain unchanged. (2). The output elasticity of capital and labour changes with time, and the structure of production function changes accordingly. (3). Technological progress moves at different speed during different period of time. (4). Technological efficiency changes with time. The different speed of these changes in different areas have also been taken into consideration.

    According to the Solow growth accounting method, productivity growth comes mainly from technological progress. According to the method used in this paper, however, productivity can be decomposed into two parts: efficiency improvement and technological progress. The former is attributable to the move toward the possible frontier of production, while the latter is attributable to the move of the possible frontier of production itself. Even without technological progress, underdeveloped countries and regions can achieve positive productivity growth by narrowing the gap between their output and optimum output (improvement of efficiency).

    This method of decomposition distinguishes, from a quantitative angle, the effect produced by economic reforms on the level and growth of long-term economic growth (Lucas, 1988). On the one hand, the level effect of economic reforms leads to growth of actual output (move toward the possible frontier of production), and on the other hand, the growth effect means that economic reform leads to sustainability of economic growth by raising the level of production in the short run and stimulating technological progress. A fundamental difference between these two effects is that level effect may disappear with the elapse of time, while growth effect will stay or even expand.

    II. Source of Data and Their Processing

    The model specified above is used to analyze the panel data of 27 Chinese provinces and autonomous regions between 1981 and 1997. The data from Tibet are incomplete. There are no data of the time sequence from Hainan because it was established as a province only in 1988. Chongqing was established as a municipality in 1996, so it was included in Sichuan Province for calculation in this paper. Preliminary graphic analysis shows that the data of the time sequence from Qinghai Province are highly questionable. For this reason, these four regions are not included in the data samples.

    The GDP data for the provinces, autonomous regions and municipalities are from the State Bureau of Statistics. The 1981-1984 statistics of labour forces are taken from the China Yearbook of Statistics, with the statistics for the period 1981-1984 obtained by the extrapolated method. In order to turn the nominal GDP data into GDP of invariant price, a price reduction index is worked out with nominal GDP and actual growth rate of GDP. The total number of the employed is used in this paper due to lack of data on the "man/hours".

    ...

    If you need the full context, please leave a message on the website.

     
    国产AV无码专区亚汌A√| 中文字幕av在线| 亚洲欧美成人久久综合中文网| 亚洲ⅴ国产v天堂a无码二区| 人妻丝袜中文无码av影音先锋专区| 亚洲中文字幕无码久久精品1| 亚洲中文字幕无码一久久区| 人妻丰满熟妇岳AV无码区HD| 日韩在线中文字幕制服丝袜| 伊人久久无码精品中文字幕| 毛片无码免费无码播放| 日韩精品无码免费专区网站| 熟妇人妻中文a∨无码| 国产AV无码专区亚洲Av| 亚洲av无码潮喷在线观看| 无码人妻久久一区二区三区蜜桃| 天堂а在线中文在线新版| 国产99久久九九精品无码| 无码人妻精品一区二区三18禁| 中文字幕在线播放| 最近2019免费中文字幕视频三| 狠狠躁天天躁中文字幕无码 | 久久久久久无码国产精品中文字幕| 国产亚洲?V无码?V男人的天堂| 无码中文字幕av免费放dvd| 精品深夜AV无码一区二区老年| 国产资源网中文最新版| 亚洲av中文无码乱人伦在线r▽| 久久久久久亚洲精品无码| 99热门精品一区二区三区无码| 久久久久成人精品无码中文字幕| 亚洲精品成人无码中文毛片不卡| 久久精品无码一区二区WWW| 中文无码一区二区不卡αv| 精品人妻V?出轨中文字幕 | 亚洲日韩中文字幕在线播放| 亚洲?v无码国产在丝袜线观看 | 中文字幕无码一区二区免费| 无码任你躁久久久久久老妇App | 人妻系列AV无码专区| 中文字幕一区二区三区乱码|